A commercial intercourse with Africa opens an inexhaustible source of wealth to the manufacturing interests of Great Britain , and to all which the slave-trade is an objection.
[I]t lays open an endless field of commerce to the British manufacturers and merchant adventurers. The manufacturing interest and the general interests are synonymous. The abolition of slavery would be in reality an [sic] universal good.
Olaudah Equiano, a freed slave campaigning for the abolition of the slave trade in the late 18th century, understood that the slave trade was as much an economic issue as it was a moral one. Hence the campaign for its abolition would need to stretch beyond moral reasoning and embrace economic interests. Over two centuries later, a combination of ethical obligations and financial incentives is once again spurring the global community into action.
The adverse changes in the environment triggered by the burning of fossil fuels have been a focus of continuing debate within scientific, political and business circles. There is a growing consensus that modern society’s insatiable appetite for energy is eroding the climate’s delicate balance, with wide-ranging effects from rising temperatures and sea levels to devastating tsunamis and hurricanes.
However, while the moral case for preserving the environment for future generations is compelling, the socioeconomic costs of reducing greenhouse gas emissions hinder the implementation of corrective measures. In E&E TV's OnPoint interview program aired on 13 December 2005, Margo Thorning, managing director of the International Council for Capital Formation, argues that European governments do not have the political will to impose energy taxes high enough, across all sectors of the economy, to force energy use down. “We found, using a broad macroeconomic analysis, that the gross domestic product of four major EU countries would be significantly reduced [if they imposed taxes high enough to hit their targets],” says Ms. Thorning. “So the economic consequences of actually trying to hit the targets are quite significant.”
The Kyoto Protocol establishes a mechanism for international trading in emissions as well as project-based mechanisms including the Clean Development Mechanism and Joint Implementation. These provide a strong incentive for economies to invest both domestically and internationally in clean energy. In addition to energy savings that would be achieved, some of the cost could be recouped by trading their emissions credits. The EU estimates that with its Emissions Trading Scheme, the cost of meeting its
Economic activities are based on scarcity in relation to supply and demand, so placing a limit on carbon emissions provides the price mechanism on which a carbon market can be built. Using the cap-and-trade system, the EU ETS rewards energy-efficient companies while simultaneously sanctioning companies that breach their carbon emissions quota. This encourages companies to develop processes and technologies that reduce carbon emissions, to the mutual benefit of both the economy and the environment.
Rapidly developing economies such as
The CDM provides the financial incentives for technologically advanced countries to share their emission-saving technologies with less developed countries that do not have emissions targets. The savings resulting from the technology transfer can be credited towards their own emissions targets. Mr. Vaitheeswaran adds that rich countries like the
Certainly, the
While environmental activists continue to pressurize governments and businesses to fulfill their moral obligations, the sound of the cash register just might convert boardroom executives into eco-warriors. Like Olaudah Equiano figured, actually.
No comments:
Post a Comment